Добавил:
Upload Опубликованный материал нарушает ваши авторские права? Сообщите нам.
Вуз: Предмет: Файл:
ГЛАВА_5_СТУДЕНТЫ.doc
Скачиваний:
0
Добавлен:
14.11.2019
Размер:
69.63 Кб
Скачать
  1. Translation from page.

Translate from page the passage expanding on the subject of the text.

Long waves and innovations

The resurgence of entrepreneurial instincts in former Eastern bloc nations might also have sur­prised Joseph Schumpeter, whose writings cel­ebrated the creative vigor of capitalism. In 1911, he proposed a long-wave theory of business cy­cles in which development is fueled when en­trepreneurs initiate such innovations as (a) discoveries of raw materials, (b) new goods or new quality in familiar products, (c) technolog­ical advances, (d) the opening of new markets, or (e) major reorganizations of industries.

Major innovations generate spinoffs, which are related inventions, mimicries of an original innovation, or the births of new industries. Such advances as microelectronics, Teflon, and laser surgery, for example, were spinoffs of the space program. Economic growth peaks by the time society fully adapts to a major innovation; satu­rated markets cannot absorb further supply in­creases or emulation of the new technology. When firms retrench, the economy slumps while awaiting fresh innovations. The next long-wave process is sparked (but only after a delay) by a new wave of innovation. Of course, minor in­novations might explain shorter cycles.

Schumpeter identified certain institutional features in a society as essential for innovation and economic vitality. First, entrepreneurs must nave broad discretion about how to operate. Second, well-developed financial markets must channel credit to entrepreneurs, allowing in­vestment in new capital and R&D even before they actually contribute anything to national in­come.

Schumpeter used railroads to illustrate major innovations. Cars, planes, and advances in agriculture have also driven U.S. economic development. More recently, computers have enabled some firms to grow to sizes that were impossible when information processing was primitive, and microprocessors have thrust an array of new consumer goods (e.g., garage door openers, electronic toys, and microwave ovens) into the realm of necessities for many Americans. Perhaps the most underrated inno­vation of the past century is the supermarket, which reduces transaction costs for an incredi­ble variety of goods. Supermarkets provide out­lets for specialized firms that would have been denied shelf space in old-fashioned general stores.

In the past few decades, economically less developed areas such as Japan, Taiwan, Hong Kong, South Korea, Malaysia, Mexico, and, most recently, China and India, have experienced dramatic growth, largely through the imple­mentation of market incentives. Schumpeter would not have been surprised by the progress made possible by competition among ambitious entrepreneurs. One major prediction extended beyond even Schumpeter's own long-wave the­ory (30 to 60 years). It seems strange, but Schumpeter, a devotee of capitalism, was almost as convinced as Marx that capitalism might ulti­mately self-destruct. However, he hypothesized a very different mechanism.

Schumpeter thought that prosperity cre­ated by capitalism (and not, as Marx thought, a capitalist depression) would ultimately create ir­resistible pressure for redistribution of income from the haves to the have-nots. This, in turn, would diminish entrepreneurial incentives, draining capitalism’s creative vigor. Thus, in essence, his most sweeping forecast was that capitalism would fall victim to its own success. Many modern economists who share Schumpeter’s enthusiasm for entrepreneurs as innovative heroes also see governmental growth in developed countries as an omen that Schumpeter’s worst fears are being realized. 3033 digits