Добавил:
Опубликованный материал нарушает ваши авторские права? Сообщите нам.
Вуз: Предмет: Файл:
Weapons of the Weak_ Everyday Forms of Peasant Resistance ( PDFDrive ).pdf
Скачиваний:
1
Добавлен:
31.07.2022
Размер:
38.92 Mб
Скачать

SEDAKA, 1967-1979 • 91

RICH AND POOR

Glaring inequalities were an integral feature of economic life in Sedaka befOre double-cropping. They remain so today. They are apparent from the most casual visual evidence of clothing, housing, fOod, furniture, kitchen or farm equipment, radios and, in a few cases now, television sets. They are, on closer inspection, produced and maintained by equally glaring disparities in the distribution of land ownership, of farm size, and hence of income.

Incomes in Sedaka were highly skewed in 1978-79. Despite the fact that there are no comparable figures fur 1967, what we do know about land and farm-size distribution then suggests inequalities of a similar magnitude at the very least. The present situation can be seen from table 4.1, which reports net income fur each household in the village, together with rice land owned and operated and the dominant occupation of the head of household. Families are ranked from poorest to richest on the basis of income per capita in the household. Readers may find it helpful to refer to this listing when they wish to identify the income, tenure status, major source of household income, party affiliation, and so forth of families who will appear and reappear throughout the text.

Using the standard government procedures to calculate per capita income-- by which children and adults are counted equally-a total of forty households, or 54 percent, ofvillage families would fall below the official poverty-line income of $572 per capita per year. A less stringent formula, employed in table 4.1, which counts infants below age six as only one-third of an adult equivalent and children aged six through twelve as two-thirds, places twenty-two households, or 30 percent, ofSedaka's families below the poverty line. It is fur these twentytwo families and the eight or ten families who have incomes just above the poverty line that the problems of fuod and daily necessities take their most severe furm. For these families, an illness of a working adult, a poor yield, a decline in harvest work, an increase in rents, or the withdrawal of a tenancy can easily spell disaster. Their income contrasts starkly with that of the best-off twentytwo families in the village. The poorest twenty-two households have an average net annual income ofM$2,291 while the richest twenty-two households earn an average of M$6,044. The contrast is more pronounced if we consider per capita

basic economic data on landholding, tenure, and social organization. Although his stay was briefer than mine and his interests necessarily more limited, his research provided me with invaluable base-line data from which to draw inferences about the effects of double-cropping. Many of the historical comparisons that fOllow are based on the infOrmation he has generously supplied. The two most important published reports in English drawing on these data are Kanzo Horii, "The Land Tenure System of Malay Padi Farmers: A Case Study ... in the State ofKedah," Developing Economies

10, no. 1 (1972): 45-73, and Rice Economy and Land Tenure in West Malaysia: A Comparative Study of Eight Villages. I.D.E. Occasional Papers Series No. 18 (Tokyo: Institute of Developing Economics, 1981).

TABLE 4.1 • Village Data by Households-Identified by Household Head and Ranked from Poorest to Richest according to Per Capita Annual Net Income

 

 

 

 

Paddy Area

Paddy Area

Status

 

 

 

 

Net Income

Net

Ownedb

Worked

by Major

Political

Membership

 

 

Per Capita

Household

(Relong)

(Relong)

Source of

Party

in Farmers'

 

 

(Adjusted)

Income"

1979

1979

Income

Affiliationc

Association

1

Razak

186

747

.25

0

laborer

UMNO

No

2

Wahid

392

1,960

0

6

tenant

UMNO

No

3

Salleh

406

2,314

1.50

5.50

tenant

PAS

No

4

Taib

413

2,063

1.25

1.25

laborer

PAS

No

5

Sukur

421

2,108

.25

.25

laborer

PAS

No

6

Mat "halus"

426

1,960

0

0

laborer

PAS

No

7

Bakri bin Haji Wahab

453

2,992

0

4.00

tenant

UMNO

No

8

Hamzah

474

2,986

2

0

laborer

PAS

No

9

Mansur

479

1,580

0

0

laborer

UMNO

No

10

Karim

480

2,218

0

2

laborer

UMNO

No

11

Pak Yah

484

3,870

0

0

laborer

PAS

No

12

Mat Sarif

485

3,190

0

3

tenant

UMNO

No

13

Midon

497

1,640

0

0

laborer

PAS

No

14

Dullah

498

2,990

0

1.50

laborer

PAS

No

15

Hasnah

520

2,081

1. 75

1.25

laborer

PAS

No

16

Tok Baba

526

2,366

10

4

owner

UMNO

No

17

Samad

539

3,236

0

8

tenant

UMNO

No

18

Rustam

544

3,429

1

2

owner

PAS

No

19

Sha'ari

548

1,260

0

.75

tenant

PAS

No

20

Salmah

560

1,120

1.25

1.25

laborer

PAS

No

21

Tok Zainah

562

1,124

2.50

1

owner

UMNO

No

22

Zin

566

3,170

.75

0

pensioner

PAS

No

23

Tok Radzi

583

3,846

0

5

tenant

PAS

No

24

Cik Puteh

614

2,826

2

4

owner

UMNO

No

25

Ishak

614

2,478

0

3

tenant

PAS

No

26

Rosni

662

3,507

0

4

tenant

PAS

No

27

Ariffin

670

2,680

0

3

tenant

UMNO

No

28

Samat

701

4,418

0

5

tenant

PAS

No

29

Nizam bin Haji Lah

712

1,424

0

3

tenant

PAS

No

30

Tok Jariah

716

1,145

1

1.50

owner

UMNO

No

31

Harun Din

717

2,152

0

.50

laborer

UMNO

No

32

Dzulkifli bin Haji Wahab

770

2,540

0

4

tenant

pagar

No

33

Mat Nasir

774

1,780

0

1.50

laborer

PAS

No

34

Mat Buyong

783

4,074

1

5

tenant

PAS

Yes

35

Lebai Hussein

784

6,272

3

6

owner

UMNO

Yes

36

Ali Abdul Rahman

803

1,846

0

2

tenant

UMNO

No

37

Tok Omar

806

3,226

0

4

tenant

UMNO

No

38

Hamid

828

3,810

9.75

0

landlord

UMNO

No

39

Onn

845

2,198

0

1

laborer

UMNO

No

40

Tok Ahmad

861

3,012

0

4

tenant

UMNO

No

41

Abdul Rahman

864

3,974

16.5

11.5

owner

UMNO

No

42

Fadzil

882

4,678

8.5

8

owner

UMNO

Yes

43

Cik Tun

938

1,876

1.5

3

owner

UMNO

No

44

Lazim

957

7,654

3

13.5

tenant

UMNO

Yes

45

Mustapha

973

2,540

3

4

owner

pagar

No

46

Tajuddin

994

3,579

0

4

tenant

UMNO

No

47

Mat Khir

1,020

5,710

0

2

tenant

UMNO

No

48

Tok Halim

1,060

1,060

6

0

landlord

UMNO

No

49

Abdul Rahim

1,083

2,490

0

3

tenant

UMNO

No

50

Cik Latifah

1,091

4,910

5

5

owner

UMNO

No

51

Jamil

1,096

6,138

6

6

owner

UMNO

Yes

52

Tok Sah Bidan

1,162

3,486

2.50

5.50

owner

UMNO

No

53

Zahid

1,169

2,688

1.50

3

\"owner

PAS

No

54

Ghani Lebai Mat

1,219

7,316

5.75

10

owner

UMNO

Yes

55

Kamil

1,246

6,230

0

15

tenant

pagar

Yes

56

Tok Mahmud

1,261

2,522

4

3

owner

PAS

No

57

Abu Hassan

1,343

6,180

3

6

salary

UMNO

Yes

58

Mat Isa

1,536

3,532

0

5

tenant

PAS

No

59

Tok Mah

1,542

5,094

7.5

8

owner

UMNO

No

60

Tok Kasim

1,569

4,708

5.5

6

owner

PAS

No

61

Tok Long

1,582

4,746

3

6

owner

UMNO

Yes

62

Haji Ngah

1,650

3,300

15

0

landlord

PAS

No

63

Shanon

1,769

5,308

4.5

5

owner

PAS

No

64

Basir

1,778

9,948

10

7

owner

UMNO

Yes

65

Ghazali

1,830

4,209

0

8.5

tenant

UMNO

No

66

Shamsul

1,845

7,380

6

8

salary

UMNO

Yes

67

Idris

2,061

6,184

7

6

owner

UMNO

Yes

68

Nor

2,137

7,692

11

11

owner

PAS

No

69

Yaakub

2,137

4,274

3

3

owner

UMNO

No

70

Haji Jaafar

2,154

6,412

15

6

owner

UMNO

Yes

71

Zaharuddin

2,226

5,120

0

5

tenant

UMNO

Yes

72

Amin

2,271

7,494

2.5

10

tenant

UMNO

Yes

73

Lebai Pendek

2,425

9,700

8

13

owner

UMNO

Yes

74

Haji Kadir

4,325

12,940

30

15

owner

PAS

No

 

 

•Net household income figures necessarily convey a level of precision that is unwarranted.

Paddy income, the major component of income

fur most households, may be calculated with some precision. Income from wage labor and sideline jobs is somewhat less accurate, although effOrts were made to double-check such figures. Thus, net household income figures should be considered fair approximations, accurate to within M$200 to M$300 in nearly all cases. Complete and accurate data might, therefOre, change the rank ordering marginally.

bJn a few cases (5) the household owns small amounts of orchard or rubber land. This landholding is not listed, but any income from it is included in the income data.

cln three cases, political affiliation is listed as pagar (the Malay word fur "fence") indicating that the household head is affiliated with no party or both parties, or, in one case, that each spouse is affiliated with a different party. Party affiliations are typically known by all villagers and their independent assessments tally almost perfectly.

SEDAKA, 1967-1979 • 95

annual income within the household; here the richest twenty-two families receive nearly fOur times M$1,867, the per capita income of poor households (M$475).

The disparity in incomes is reflected, as one would expect, in the disparity of secure control over the key factor of production: land. Between them, the twenty-two poorest families in Sedaka own only 22. 5 relong of land-an average of barely 1 relong (1 relong = .71 acres). Keeping in mind that the standard fur a poverty-line income from paddy farming alone is a minimum of 4 relong, the poorest households own scarcely one-quarter of the land required to provide fur their essential needs. The wealthiest twenty-two households, on the other hand, own a total of more than 142 relong, giving them an average owned holding of nearly 6.5 relong. The disparity in farm size, which includes land rented in, at the two poles of the village hierarchy is actually slightly less skewed only because the land owned by many richer families makes it unnecessary for them to rent in additional paddy acreage. Nevertheless, the poorest twenty-two families are able to rent in only enough land to give them an average farm size of less than two relong (1.89) while the richest families have an average farm size of 7.25 relong. Put another way, relatively well-to-do households actually manage to rent in almost as much additional paddy land as poor families, although they need it far less.

In fact, the figures on land ownership, seen from a slightly different perspective, reveal far more glaring inequities. If we disregard fur a moment the income figures in table 4.1 and simply count the households that own no paddy land whatever, thirty families (41 percent) fall in this category. 6 Thus nearly half the village lacks legal control over the major productive asset in rice farming. If we take the half (thirty-seven families) of Sedaka's households who own the least land, we find that they own a mere 7 relong between them. As the total rice land owned by all villagers is 235.5 relong, we have a situation in which half the village owns less than 3 percent of locally owned paddy land. The ten biggest village landowners, by contrast, represent only 14 percent of the households but own outright 133.75 relong, or 47 percent of the rice land owned by villagers.

It is possible to compare the land ownership pattern in 1979 with the situation in 1967 and thereby assess the impact of double-cropping and new technology. There is essentially no change over the past thirteen years, that is, no change in a distribution of land ownership that was, at the outset, extremely skewed. Once account is taken of the increase in the village population from fifty-six to seventy-four households, even the marginal improvement in the proportion of land owned by land-poor households proves to be misleading. Thus, by 1979 the land-poor half of the village was comprised of nine more families than in

6. This finding places Sedaka close to the region-wide norm for the percentage of pure tenants and pure wage laborers in Muda's paddy sector, which is 37 percent. See chap. 3.

96 o SEDAKA, 1967-1979

1967, and among them they owned a negligible 3 percent of the rice land. There are today more families (thirty) owning no paddy land in Sedaka than there were in 1967 (twenty-seven), despite the fact that the proportion oflandless households has declined somewhat.

The relation between land ownership and income in this one-crop economy is obvious. Only fuur of the richest twenty-two families own no land. In all fuur cases the anomaly is accounted fur by various combinations of small family size and outside wages and above all by the renting in of paddy land averaging more than 8 relong per household. For that half of the village with the lowest incomes, conversely, land ownership is conspicuous by its absence. Roughly 60 percent of these poor villagers own no land at all and only three families own more than 2 relong.

The distribution of ownership within the village in paddy land is unlikely to shift markedly in the near future. Higher and steadier yields, when coupled with the traditional Malay reluctance to part with land, has served to slow dramatically the process of land concentration through indebtedness. In the three decades befOre 1970, Haji Kaclir (#74), now the largest landowner in the village, managed to purchase 25 relong in eight separate transactions from smallholders with insurmountable debts. Although he remains as avid for land as in the past, he has not added anything to his holdings since the beginning of double-cropping. Not only are the small landowners whose land he might covet less likely to find themselves in such dire straits, but the market fur rental land is now so buoyant that a hard-pressed smallholder can clear his debts more easily by renting his land out fur several seasons at a time (pajak) and retain title.

By the same token, the marked increase in paddy-land prices has also elim-

TABLE 4.2 o Distribution of Ownership of Paddy Land in Sedaka,

1967-1979

 

1967

1979

Total No. of Village Households

56

74

Land-poor

 

 

Percentage of total villager-owned paddy land held by land-poor

 

 

half of village

1%

3%

-total area (relong)

1.25

7.00

-average owned per household (relong)

.04

.19

-no. of households

28

37

Land-rich

 

 

Percentage of total villager-owned paddy land held by top 14%

 

 

of village landowners

54%

57%

-total area (relong)

114.50

133.75

-average owned per household (relong)

14.3

13.3

-no. of households

8

10

Total paddy land owned by villagers (relong)

210.25

235.5

SEDAKA, 1967-1979 • 97

inated the possibility of upward mobility fur all but the richest. Such upward mobility through land purchase was certainly not common, even before doublecropping, but five villagers who now own from 3 to 7 relong had managed to buy at least a portion of that land. Since 1970 not a single smallholder in this category has added to his holdings. And if this category is effectively barred from purchasing land, it fullows that those with less than 3 relong of their own, which is to say most of the village households, do not even contemplate the possibility.

Since double-cropping began, only nine villagers have either bought or sold land. The pattern of these transactions reveals not only the diminished pace of land concentration but the fact that the process, if slowed, still moves in the same direction. The buyers are without exception well-to-do, and the sellers are predominantly poor. Four villagers have, since 1970, bougl1t a total of 19.25 relong, much of it located outside the village. Daud, the son of the village headman, Haji Jaafar (#70), has with his father's help purchased 8 relong, including 3 relong from a villager. Nor (#68) has bought 8.25 relong with the help of his father (an outsider who already owns over 50 relong), all of it land at some distance from the village. Amin (#73) has from his own savings purchased 2.5 relong of local land from a wealthy landowning Haji in a neighboring village. Taken collectively, these three households illustrate which class in the village is still able to add to its holdings; they represent three of the six richest households in Sedaka. The one exception, Fadzil (#42), who bought 2. 5 relong from another villager, is the exception that proves the rule. While he is not among the wealthiest ten villagers, he does own 8 relong, and his currently modest income is simply a reflection of the fact that he had to lease out much of his land to raise the capital fur this purchase.

Five villagers have sold land. The two largest sales, for 5 and 10 relong respectively, were made by villagers who were admitted to government settlement schemes and were liquidating their local holdings. 7 All but 2.5 relong of this land was sold to wealthy outsiders fur premium prices. A third sale, of 3 relong, illustrates the circumstances under which poor families may still have to part with their land. Mat "Halus" 's wife (#6) was co-heir, along with at least eight other brothers and sisters, of 3 relong, The heirs could not agree on a mutual division of paddy fields and after a year decided to sell the land and divide the proceeds. The land passed to Daud, son of Haji Jaafar, that is, from one of the poorest households to one of the richest. The two remaining sales were made by two poor widowed sisters, Hasnah (# 15) and Salmah (#20), each of whom sold half a relong to a much wealthier brother living in a nearby village. Both sales were made under rather exceptional circumstances; normally neither sister would

7. It is far more common fur those who leave fur settlement schemes to retain their local land and rent it out.

98 • SEDAKA, 1967-1979

have considered selling. 8 In all five cases, the paddy land sold has passed into the hands of the well-to-do or rich. Two of the sellers were well-off themselves, and their selling could reasonably be seen as investment decisions. For the others, however, the sales were a further step toward landlessness.

The inequities described in a pattern of land ownership can occasionally be mitigated by the actual pattern of tenure. That is, if those with the largest holdings rent out much of their paddy land to poorer farmers, the actual distribution of farm size may be more equitable than ownership statistics would imply. In the case ofSedaka, the actual distribution of cultivated acreage, though it is more equitable than ownership, is nevertheless highly skewed. The ten largest farms, for example, which constitute no more than 14 percent of village households, cultivate a total of 115. 5 relong, or 36 percent of the total paddy land cultivated by villagers. The average size of their farms is 11.6 relong (8.2 acres). The half of the village (thirty-seven families) with the smallest farm sizes, by contrast, cultivates only 58.75 relong, or a mere 18 percent of the paddy land worked by villagers. 9 Their average farm size is only 1.6 relong, or slightly more than 1 acre. Here we have a replication of the general situation in the Muda region: much of the village's farm population does not have access to the productive resources that would allow them to achieve a reliable subsistence. While their small plots may provide many of them with their daily rice, they could not make ends meet without the cash they earn as wage laborers in the paddy fields or elsewhere. ·

As with the figures on land ownership, it is possible to contrast the distribution of farm size in 1979 with the situation in 1967, using Horii's data for the earlier period (table 4. 3). The relative stability of the percentage distributions masks far more dramatic changes. The small farmers in Sedaka have quite literally lost ground. Their share of the total land farmed has diminished from nearly one-quarter to less than one-fifth; the total acreage they farm has declined by

8.The exceptional circumstances were that still another brother who lives on a government rubber estate elsewhere in Kedah and who inherited adjacent land, which he came to farm, simply took over these two small plots and farmed them himself. All entreaties failed and the two sisters, afraid to go to the police or courts, given their brother's reputation fur violence, finally decided to sell their plots to another brother, since they had been unable to cultivate them fur five seasons. The brother who bought the land was, as of 1981, still unable to farm it and had begun a costly law suit to enfOrce his title. The case illustrates the tenuous influence of the state and its agents in enfOrcing property law where anyone is willing to use violence to frustrate its working. According to villagers, however, it is quite an exceptional case.

9.I have included ten families who farm no land at all. While the usual practice in computing farm-size distributions is to include only those families who cultivate at least some land, the results of this procedure underestimate the extent of land hunger. Seven of the ten families in question would jump at the chance to rent in land if it were available; only three are retired cultivators who choose not to farm.

SEDAKA, 1967-1979 • 99

TABLE 4.3 • Distribution of Paddy Farm Size in Sedaka,

1967-1979

 

 

1967

1979

Total No. of Village Households

56

74

Small Farms*

 

 

Percentage of total villager-farmed paddy land cultivated by

 

that half of village with smallest farm sizes

24%

18%

-total area (relong)

85.0

58.75

-average farm si?e per household (relong)

3.0

1.6

-no. of households

28

37

Large Farms

 

 

Percentage of total villager-farmed paddy land cultivated by

 

that 14% of village with largest farm size

40%

36%

-total area (relong)

142.5

175.5

-average farm size per household (relong)

17.8

11.6

-no. of households

8

10

Total paddy land cultivated by villagers (relong)

357.75

323.25

*Includes, fur 1979, 10 families with no farmland. See n. 9.

nearly one-third. Coupled with the growth in the population of the village, this has cut the average farm size for this hard-pressed sector of the village from 3 relong before double-cropping to only 1.6 relong in 1979. This change alone has been sufficient to more than negate the additional income that doublecropping could have provided. 10 It would appear from the figures that largescale farmers have lost considerable ground as well, especially in terms of average farm size. Much of this loss, however, can be traced to a single farmer, Kamil (#55), who in 1967 rented in an amazing 38 relong, most of which has since been reclaimed by the outside landowner and distributed to his heirs.

The reasons for this basic structural change, which threatens the livelihood of the poorest villagers, are important and complex enough to merit extended analysis later; a few reasons have already been mentioned in the preceding chapter. Here it is sufficient to note that demography has played a role. Many rather poor families who have moved into the village have either no land to farm or, more typically, only a relong or two. The process of inheritance has also meant that

10. Double-cropping does not, other things equal, simply double income. The necessary inputs fur double-cropping, including fertilizer, tractor preparation, and increased labor costs, drain away a portion of the new gains. In Kedah, it was initially estimated that the net return for rice land was raised by 60 percent because of irrigation. Thus 1.6 relong would, if double-cropped, be equivalent to 2.66 relong of single-cropped land. The decline by half in the average holding of small farmers in Sedaka has thus left them worse off in terms of farm income despite the fact that they harvest two crops a year.