Добавил:
Опубликованный материал нарушает ваши авторские права? Сообщите нам.
Вуз: Предмет: Файл:

Scheer Solar Economy Renewable Energy for a Sustainable Global Future (Earthscan, 2005)

.pdf
Скачиваний:
42
Добавлен:
22.08.2013
Размер:
2.42 Mб
Скачать

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

EXPLOITING SOLAR RESOURCES 81

Sunlight

 

 

Solar cell

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Inverter

 

 

Electricity

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Wind

 

 

 

 

Rotor

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Generator

 

Electricity

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Fossil

 

 

 

 

Combustion

 

 

Heat

 

 

Steam

 

Turbine

 

 

Generator

 

Electricity

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

fuel

 

 

chamber

 

 

 

 

Cooling

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Emissions filter

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Waste storage

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

and disposal

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Nuclear

 

 

 

Reactor

 

 

 

Heat

 

 

Steam

 

Turbine

 

 

Generator

 

Electricity

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

fuel

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Cooling

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Storage of

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

nuclear waste

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Figure 2.2 Internal processing steps involved in solar and fossil fuel/nuclear electricity generation

Short chains: the greater productivity potential of renewable energy

There are greater opportunities for productive energy use where power can be generated at a reduced technical cost. For renewable energy, however, these opportunities have hitherto been realized only in isolated niches – for instance, in low-end applications like pocket calculators, in the so-called ‘passive use’ of solar energy for heating and cooling buildings, in the solar collectors already installed on countless roofs in places like Greece and Israel, or in the ‘solar home systems’ in use in rural regions of developing countries, where generation from PV, even at this early stage in their development, is already more cost-effective than conventional power generation and distribution methods. Using PV saves on the cost of purchasing generators and the diesel to run them, not to mention erecting expensive overland distribution cables.

In the industrialized countries, such examples are regarded as side-issues or interim solutions for less developed countries. This dismissiveness means that the enormous opportunities that shorter supply chains present for increased productivity in the industrialized countries are all too quickly overlooked. Of course, for these opportunities to be realized, there must first

82 CAPTIVITY OR LIBERATION

be a conceptual break with the idea that what worked for fossil fuels will work for renewable energy. The structures required for fossil fuel energy are not compatible with the economic requirements of an electricity supply based on solar energy.

Solar power: technology without technocracy

With very few exceptions, centralized power generation from solar sources would effectively negate the advantages accruing from a decentralized energy supply (the subject of Parts III and IV of this book). It would be daft to close down existing hydropower dams; large-scale solar thermal plants to supply tropical cities make sense. Equally, the resulting disconnection from the regional resource base makes biomass-fired power stations of over 100 MW nonsensical; nor are large tidal power plants along great stretches of coastline to be recommended, when wind power provides a simpler, less costly solution more in keeping with the natural landscape.

In any case, even centralized solar power generation in sunnier parts of the world would inevitably need to be supplemented by local PV, wind, small-scale hydro and biomass plant. Yet the history of power generation and supply teaches us that although large-scale generation plant may be technically compatible with small-scale plant, combining the two produces structural conflict. Operators of large-scale plant need to run at full capacity to recoup their costs; the unpredictable output of small-scale producers is an irritant. There is little reason to assume that operators of large-scale solar power plant would behave any differently towards smaller suppliers than operators of nuclear and coal-fired plants. In the case of fossil fuels, the obsession with large-scale production and supply is a reflection of the underlying economic realities. In the case of solar power, the same obsession would be ill-considered, an expression of the industrial fantasies typical of the 20th century.

Grand schemes following the pattern of concentrated generation and supply set by fossil fuel power generation have been and continue to be entertained in respect of renewable energy. They are the product of a paradigm that can conceive only of individual large-scale remedies for large-scale problems.

EXPLOITING SOLAR RESOURCES 83

One example of this was the proposal of the Munich-based architect and author Herman Sörgel, first presented at a 1931 exhibition of architecture in Berlin, to construct a dam right across the Straits of Gibraltar to control the flow of water from the Atlantic into the more low-lying Mediterranean. The idea was to build a gigantic hydropower plant to supply Europe with electricity, while at the same time lowering the level of the Mediterranean to reclaim additional land from the sea along the Mediterranean coast and create a land bridge between Europe and North Africa. The Adriatic was to become dry land; Naples would have ceased to be a port. The project was much talked about; it fascinated Hitler as much as Mussolini.7 No thought was given to the incalculable consequences of reshaping the Mediterranean ecosystem on such a scale; the project was too tempting to geopolitical ambitions of making North Africa both a part of and, in conjunction with the greening of the Sahara, the breadbasket of Europe.

Another, more contemporary example is the GENESIS project (Global Energy Network Equipped with Solar Cells and International Superconductor Grids) that some minds are toying with. The idea is to construct a global belt of linked solar power stations running along the equator to supply the entire world energy demand through a superconducting distribution grid. The supposed advantage would be an uninterrupted supply of solar electricity, because the difference between day and night and seasonal variation in output between hemispheres would cancel each other out.8 But the result would be a hypercentralized global energy supply, the global dominance of one generation technology with the longest supply chain imaginable and colossal infrastructural costs. It is a product of technological megalomania with absolutely no conception of the sociopolitics of energy supply.

A third and similar example is NASA engineer Peter E Glaser’s concept of an orbiting ‘solar farm’, which also crops up in discussion from time to time. Electricity for all Earth’s inhabitants would be produced from PV platforms, orbiting the Earth, with a total surface area of many square kilometres, free of the limitations of diurnal and seasonal cycles. Generative efficiency would be very high because even incident

84 CAPTIVITY OR LIBERATION

sunlight outside the angle of refraction (a product of the Earth’s curvature) could be exploited. The current produced would be beamed back to the ground in the form of microwaves with a ground footprint several kilometres in diameter. These would be picked up by a ground station almost 200 km2 in size, converted back into electricity and fed into the distribution grid.9 The same applies to this concept as to the GENESIS project: it may be technically feasible, but otherwise impractical, with no consideration of risk, economic viability or social consequences, and a failure to appreciate the real opportunities that solar power presents.

Proposals that turn a local resource free of supply chain dependency into a hypercentralized generation and supply system, maximizing dependency, are the product of a technocratic approach that has no regard for social context; an approach which, even without such engineering mega-projects, has already led to the shaping of society to fit technology, rather than – finally – adapting technology to meet real needs. Even the idea of using Saharan solar power to produce hydrogen for export, although on a considerably less monstrous scale than GENESIS project or solar power satellites, fails to do justice to the economic, social and political dimensions of solar power. A resource that is universally available across the planet without recourse to extended supply chains need not and should not for any reason be first centralized under oligopolistic or monopolistic business structures before being redistributed to consumers at large. We must learn and understand that it is not necessary to take circuitous and technically complex routes when there are direct, simple solutions available. It is only possible to understand and harness the social and economic capacities of technology if we take an untechnocratic approach to it.

De-monopolization and re-regionalization through solar resources

The dynamics of the drive towards business concentration is thought to be the dominant force in economic development, and, indeed, more and more industrial sectors are going down

EXPLOITING SOLAR RESOURCES 85

this route, even those for which concentration is not imposed by the resource base, as it is in the case of the fossil fuel and mineral resource industry described in Chapter 1. Many economic analysts therefore assume that the introduction of solar resources will also be followed by a process of business concentration, and in consequence many also view local installations of solar generation plant as merely the precursor to a development whose end-point will be solar resource plantations in areas of high insolation such as North Africa. In actual fact, the scope for concentration with a solar resource base is limited. Indeed, the dominant force may well be the very difficulty of monopolizing solar resources, thus turning conventional and seemingly universally applicable experiences of economic processes on their head. Mathematically speaking, it follows that the equivalent to a 1000 MW power station would be – depending on their individual ratings – 2000–4000 wind turbines, 1 million solar panels, or 50 large or 5000 small biomass plants; in practical terms, the equivalent energy production would be achieved using a combination of these sources.

The difference between the conventional energy industry with its four corporate pillars – the oil, coal, gas and uranium extraction and trading companies, the power station operators and the (in most cases identical) operators of the distribution grids, the power station construction industry and the investment banks that underwrite all the above – and renewable energy is that, in the latter case, only one sector is exposed to concentration and monopoly: the manufacture and construction of plant (ie, solar collectors, solar cells, wind turbines and biomass plants).

If renewable energy sources ever come to dominate the market, then the rump of the industrial webs described above, the fossil fuel extraction and trading companies, will slowly dwindle away. There will be nothing to replace the niche currently occupied by companies that extract or supply fossil fuels if fossil fuels come to be displaced by solar heating, sunlight, wind, waves and water currents. As Franz Alt very neatly puts it, ‘the sun sends no bills’.10 The basic problem that fossil fuel companies have is that sunlight and wind cannot

86 CAPTIVITY OR LIBERATION

be patented and sold under licence. Comprehensive use of renewable energy would take the wind from the sails of an economic globalization and industrial concentration process driven by the scarcity of fossil fuel reserves. This alone would spark a process of de-concentration, de-monopolization and the re-regionalization of economic structures.

The two spiders in the fossil energy industry web – the operators of power stations and electricity and gas distribution grids – will also have no further role to play in a decentralized energy supply based on solar power. Large power stations need large companies to run them; small local plants have no such need. Once the transition to electricity supply from renewable sources can no longer be stopped, the power companies will naturally seek to gain control of these sources. In the case of PV, the highly decentralized nature of the plant makes this an essentially futile exercise. They will have more success with wind, especially with windfarms and offshore installations in coastal waters – how much success they would have depends on the extent to which the laws regulating the energy market favour this. But as generation plant for renewable energy is subject to natural limitations – the effective maximum capacity for individual wind turbines, for example, cannot be much more than 5 MW – power plant operation will no longer be purely the preserve of large companies. Provided that the market is freely accessible, many new types of enterprise are likely: local enterprise, on-site generation by companies, producer cooperatives and innumerable individual suppliers on a regional and local level. The politically and economically explosive potential of renewable energy is its universal availability, as this eliminates the dependency of both society and political institutions on power companies and reduces the influence that those companies can exert. Every large-scale power station decommissioned, every new local plant constructed and above all every improvement in power storage technology reduces the central role played by the national grid, to the point at which it becomes superfluous.

The economies of scale, which have favoured concentrated business structures because of their ability to mass-produce cheap consumer goods and so squeeze out smaller producers,

EXPLOITING SOLAR RESOURCES 87

do not apply to renewable energy. The rise of renewable energy disrupts two of the fossil fuel spiders’ strongest webs, and the third web, the dominant role played by the large investment banks in the energy industry, is at least weakened. In a decentralized market, all potential investors, not just banks, can be sources of finance; the large investment banks will be just one player among many.

As mentioned, the market for renewable energy plant remains open to concentration and monopolization. It is possible that, following an initial boom, the global market for solar panels and accessories, solar collectors, wind turbines and biomass plants will come to be dominated by a very few firms. For the power station construction industry, this could even present a golden opportunity for diversification, provided they can make the leap from catering to a few large clients to serving many small ones. For PV and solar collectors, the customer base will be larger even than that of the car industry. That notwithstanding, manufacturers of solar generation plant will not be able to completely dominate the market. They will be dependent on a multi-billion-customer client base with a diverse demand structure for various panels and integrated systems. There will be scope for a broad spectrum of manufacturing and distribution firms, and an even broader palette of technical engineering and installation services.

The representatives of the fossil energy industry have been written out of the script for the renewable energy story, or allotted at most a secondary role; the market for renewable energy will no longer have a niche for conventional sources – at least, not with turnover at high as it is at present. Conventional energy companies are bound to old fossil fuel structures by the sheer scale of their investments; their business models, based on large-scale industrial plant, will prove their own undoing in the transition to renewable energy. A solar resource base makes it impossible to retain or ever re-create the power structure that has hitherto prevailed in the energy sector. The extent to which industrial concentration and monopolization is inevitable with fossil fuels and avoidable or impossible with solar energy is compared in Table 2.2.

Table 2.2 Can industrial concentration and monopoly structures be avoided?

 

Nuclear

Coal/gas/

Biomass

PV

Wind

Small-scale

Solar

Large-scale

Hydrogen

Hydrogen

 

power

oil

 

 

power

hydro

heating

hydro/solar

from solar

from solar

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

thermal

power

power

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

plants

(heavy

(light

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

industry)

industry)

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Primary energy

No

No

Yes

Trade in primary energy

No

No

Yes

Processing

No

No

Yes

No

Yes

Plant manufacture

No

No

No

No

No

No

Yes

No

No

No

Power station operation

No

No

Yes

Yes

Yes

Yes

No

Yes

Yes

Power distribution/trading

No

No

Yes

Yes

Yes

Yes

No

No

Yes

Plant finance

No

No

Yes

Yes

Yes

Yes

Yes

No

No

Yes

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

No: Industrial concentration and monopolization are inevitable (except for combined heat and power plant).

Yes: Industrial concentration and monopolization are technically and politically avoidable or impossible.

IBERATIONL OR APTIVITYC 88

EXPLOITING SOLAR RESOURCES 89

The short supply chains for renewable energy sources will end the pressure to globalize that comes from the fossil resource base. The dense interconnections between individual energy companies and between energy companies and other industries that result from fossil fuel supply chains will no longer be necessary. Shorter renewable energy supply chains also make it impossible to dominate entire economies. Renewable energy will liberate society from fossil fuel dependency and from the webs spun by the spiders of the fossil economy.

PA R T II

THE PATHOLOGICAL

POLITICS OF FOSSIL

RESOURCES

If the world continues to see fossil resources as indispensable and the alternatives as unrealistic, then it will continue to shrug off the dire consequences as unavoidable. The matter barely seems to merit a second thought. While the environmental consequences of energy use, resource costs, questions of efficiency and productivity and the longer-term availability of energy sources are all topics for discussion among politicians with environmental and energy portfolios, the standard response is to seek fossil fuel replacements for fossil fuel resources. The current focus is on natural gas as a replacement for crude oil, coal and nuclear power. Renewable energy is seen as a minor player in energy provision, and renewable resources are thought even less important.

That goes not just for the industrialized world, but also for the industrializing economies of the developing world. The industrialized countries’ migration to ever more complex industrial technology, larger-scale supply systems and different patterns of energy and resource use has taken place gradually, over many decades. In the developing world the transition to modern energy systems has come as a sudden jump from a rural agrarian society to centralized industry. Developing countries have consequently suffered much more acute social and economic stress than the established developed countries. Nevertheless, this stress is generally not perceived as intrinsic to a fossil fuel and mineral resource base. The myths of the

Соседние файлы в предмете Экономика