Добавил:
Upload Опубликованный материал нарушает ваши авторские права? Сообщите нам.
Вуз: Предмет: Файл:
david_Introduction_to_behavioral_economics.pdf
Скачиваний:
50
Добавлен:
26.03.2016
Размер:
12.18 Mб
Скачать

 

 

 

 

 

18

 

TRANSACTION UTILITY AND CONSUMER PRICING

take on a life of its own, so that rather than simply losing some money, we lose the money and have an unpleasant meal to boot. In this chapter we discuss Richard Thalers notion of transaction utility and resulting behavioral anomalies. Transaction utility can be dened as the utility one receives for feeling one has received greater value in a transaction than one has given away in paying for the good. This leads to three prominent anomalies: the sunk cost fallacy, at-rate bias, and reference-dependent preferences.

Rational Choice with Fixed and Marginal Costs

Economists are often taught about the impact of xed costs on choice through the prot- maximization model. As we saw in Chapter 1, the rm generally faces the following problem:

max pf x − rx − C

2 1

x

 

which is solved by x*, where price times the slope of the production function is equal to the cost of inputs, p f xx = r. In this case, the xed cost C does not enter into the solution condition. Thus, whether xed costs increase or decrease, so long as the rm chooses positive production levels, the level of production remains the same. The xed cost does affect the amount of prot, but it does not affect the amount of inputs required to maximize prots.

The same need not be the case under utility maximization. Consider a rational consumer who could consume two goods, where consuming one of the goods requires that the consumer pay a xed amount for access to a good, plus some amount for each piece consumed. This is generally referred to as a two-part tariff. One example might be a phone plan that charges a xed amount per month, plus a fee for each text message sent. Linear pricing, or charging a xed amount for each unit of the good, can be thought of as a special case of the two-part tariff where the xed amount is set to zero. We will assume that the second good is priced linearly. Flat-rate pricing, where consumers are allowed to consume as much as they like for a xed fee, can be considered a special case of the two-part tariff where the per-piece rate has been set to zero. The consumers problem can be written as

max U x1, x2

2 2

x1, x2

 

subject to the budget constraint

 

p0x1 + p1x1 + p2x2 ≤ y,

2 3

where x1 0 is the amount of the two-part tariff good, x2 0 is the amount of the linearly priced good, Ux1, x2 is the consumers utility of consumption as a function of the amount consumed, p0 is the xed cost of access, p1 is the per-unit price of consumption for the two-part tariff good, p2 is the per-unit cost of the linearly priced good, and y is the total available budget for consumption. Finally, x1 is an indicator of

 

 

 

 

Rational Choice with Fixed and Marginal Costs

 

19

 

whether the consumer has decided to consume any of the two-part tariff good, with x1 = 1 if x1 is positive and zero otherwise. We assume for now that the consumer always gains positive utility for consuming additional amounts of good 2.

If the at fee p0 is set equal to zero, this problem becomes the standard two-good consumption problem found in any standard microeconomics textbook. The solution in this case requires that the consumer optimize by consuming at the point of tangency between the highest utility level indifference curve that intersects at least one point of the budget constraint as presented in Chapter 1.

If both the at fee and the linear price are positive, consumers will only purchase good 1 if doing so allows them to obtain a higher level of utility. If the rst good is not purchased, then the budget constraint implies that consumers will consume as much of good 2 as they can afford, x2 = yp2, with a corresponding level of utility U0, x2. If the consumer purchases at least some of the two-part tariff good, the consumer decision problem functions much like the standard utility-maximization problem, where the budget constraint has been shifted in reecting a loss in budget of p0. This problem is represented in Figure 2.1. In Figure 2.1, the consumer can choose not to consume good 1 and instead consume at x2 on the outermost budget constraint (solid line representing y = p1x1 + p2x2, or equivalently x2 = y − p1x1p1) and obtain utility U0, x2, or she can nd the greatest utility possible along the innermost budget constraint (dashed line representing y = p0 + p1x1 + p2x2, or equivalently x2 = y − p0 − p1x1p1) and obtain utility Ux*1 , x*2. If the indifference curve that passes through the point Ux*1 , x*2 intersects the x2 axis below the point x2, then the consumer is better off not purchasing any of good 1 and avoiding the xed cost. In this case, pictured in Figure 2.1, increasing the xed fee cannot alter consumption because the good associated with the fee is not purchased. Decreasing the fee shifts the dashed budget curve out, potentially reaching a point where it is optimal to consume both goods.

x2 x2

x2*

x2 = (y p0 p1x1)/p2

x1*

U = U(0, x2)

U = U(x1*, x2*) x2 = (y p1x1)/p2

x1

FIGURE 2.1

Utility Maximization with a Two-Part Tariff: A Corner Solution

 

 

 

 

 

20

 

TRANSACTION UTILITY AND CONSUMER PRICING

x2 x2

 

x2*

FIGURE 2.2

 

 

Utility Maximization

 

 

with a Two-Part Tar-

 

x2 = (y p0 p1x1)/p2

iff: An Internal

 

 

 

x1*

Solution

 

U = U(x1*, x2*)

U = U(0, x2)

x2 = (y p1x1)/p2 x1

Alternatively, in Figure 2.2, the indifference curve that passes through the point Ux1*, x2* does not intersect the x2 axis below the point x2, and thus a greater level of utility can be obtained by consuming both goods and paying the xed access fee. Increasing or decreasing the fee can alter the consumption of both goods as the tangency points forming the income expansion path shift either northwest or southeast along the budget curve. However, if both goods are normal, more of each good should be purchased as the xed fee is decreased.

Finally, if the per-unit price for good 1 is zero, as would be the case at an all-you-can- eat buffet, the budget constraint can be written as p2x2 ≤ y if good 1 is not consumed and as p2x2 ≤ y − p0 if it is. These budget constraints are illustrated in Figure 2.3. As before, if both goods are consumed, then the highest utility is obtained along the indifference curve that is tangent to the budget constraint, as in Figure 2.3. Since the budget constraint is at, this can only occur at a bliss point for good 1. A bliss point is an amount of consumption such that consuming any more or any less will result in a lower level of utility. Given that a person can consume as much of good 1 as she would like after paying the xed price, if there were no bliss point, the consumer would choose to consume innite amounts, a solution that is infeasible in any real-world scenario. Consuming both goods is always the optimal solution if the indifference curve that is tangent to the lower budget constraint intersects the x2 axis above the upper budget constraint as pictured in Figure 2.3. The alternative is depicted in Figure 2.4, where the indifference curve tangent to the lower budget constrain intersects the x2 axis below the upper budget constraint. In this case, none of good 1 is consumed and consumption of good 2 is x2 = yp.

In the case that both goods are consumed, increasing the xed price has the same impact as reducing the total budget (Figure 2.3). If the two goods are complements or substitutes, then the marginal utility of consumption for good 1 will be altered by adjusting the amount of good 2 consumed. In this case, increasing the xed price reduces the amount of good 2 consumed, which necessarily moves the bliss point for good 1

 

 

 

 

Fixed versus Sunk Costs

 

21

 

x2

U > U(x1*, x2*)

x2*

U = U(x1*, x2*)

x1*

x2 x2

x2 = y/p2

U < U(x1*, x2*)

x2 = (y p0)/p2

x1

x2 = y/p2

U = U(0, x2)

U = U(x1*, x2*)

x2 = (y p0)/p2

x1

FIGURE 2.3

Utility Maximization with Flat-Rate Pricing: An Internal Solution

FIGURE 2.4

Utility Maximization with Flat-Rate Pricing: A Corner Solution

through the change in marginal utility for good 1. Alternatively, if the two goods are neither substitutes nor complements but are independent, then increasing or decreasing consumption of good 2 should have no impact on the marginal utility for good 1. In this case, no matter what the level of the xed price is, the amount of good 1 consumed should be the same so long as it is positive.

Fixed versus Sunk Costs

A concept that is related to, though distinct from, xed costs is sunk costs (Figure 2.4). At the time of a decision, a xed cost may be avoided either by not choosing the good

Соседние файлы в предмете [НЕСОРТИРОВАННОЕ]