Добавил:
Опубликованный материал нарушает ваши авторские права? Сообщите нам.
Вуз: Предмет: Файл:
Mark International Macroeconomics and Finance Theory and Empirical Methods.pdf
Скачиваний:
85
Добавлен:
22.08.2013
Размер:
2.29 Mб
Скачать

4.2. THE ONE-MONEY MONETARY ECONOMY

113

you did in (3.9) for the monetary model, the equity price—dividend ratio can be expressed as the present discounted value of future consumption growth raised to the power 1 −γ. You can then get an explicit solution once you make an assumption about the stochastic process governing output. This will be covered in section 4.5 below.

An important point to note is that there is no actual asset trading in the Lucas model. Agents hold their investments forever and never rebalance their portfolios. The asset prices produced by the model are shadow prices that must be respected in order for agents to willingly to hold the outstanding equity shares according to (4.21).

4.2The One-Money Monetary Economy

In this section we introduce a single world currency. The economic environment can be thought of as a two-sector closed economy. The idea is to introduce money without changing the real equilibrium that we characterized above. One of the di culties in getting money into the model is that the people in the barter economy get along just Þne without it. An unbacked currency in the Arrow—Debreu world that generates no consumption payo s will not have any value in equilibrium. To get around this problem, Lucas prohibits barter in the monetary economy and imposes a ‘cash-in-advance’ constraint that requires people to use money to buy goods. As we enter period t the following speciÞc cash-in-advance transactions technology must be adhered to.

1.xt and yt are revealed.

2.λt, the exogenous stochastic gross rate of change in money is re-

vealed. The total money supply Mt, evolves according to Mt = λtMt−1. The economy-wide increment ∆Mt = (λt −1)Mt−1, is distributed evenly to the home and foreign individuals where each agent receives the lump-sum transfer ∆M2 t = (λt − 1)Mt2−1 .

3.A centralized securities market opens where agents allocate their wealth towards stock purchases and the cash that they will need to purchase goods for consumption. To distinguish between the aggregate money stock Mt and the cash holdings selected by agents,

114

CHAPTER 4. THE LUCAS MODEL

denote individual’s choice variables by lower case letters, mt and mt . Securities market closes.

4.Decentralized goods trading now takes place in the ‘shopping mall.’ Each household is split into ‘worker—shopper’ pairs. The shopper takes the cash from security markets trading and buys x and y−goods from other stores in the mall (shoppers are not allowed to buy from their own stores). The home-country worker collects the x− endowment and o ers it for sale in an x−good store in the ‘mall.’ The y−goods come from the foreign country ‘worker’ in the foreign country who collects and sells the y−endowment in the mall. The goods market closes.

5.The cash value of goods sales are distributed to stockholders as dividends. Stockholders carry these nominal dividend payments into the next period.

The state of the world is the gross growth rate of home output, foreign output, and money (gt, gt , λt), and is revealed prior to trading. Because the within-period uncertainty is revealed before any trading takes place, the household can determine the precise amount of money it needs to Þnance the current period consumption plan. As a result, it is not necessary to carry extra cash from one period to the next. If the (shadow) nominal interest rate is always positive, households will make sure that all the cash is spent each period.4

To formally derive the domestic agent’s problem, let Pt be the nominal price of xt. Current-period wealth is comprised of dividends from last period’s goods sales, the market value of ex-dividend equity shares

4It may seem strange to talk about the interest rate and bonds since individuals do not hold nor trade bonds. That is because bonds are redundant assets in the current environment and consequently are in zero net supply. But we can compute the shadow interest rate to keep the bonds in zero net supply. The equilibrium interest rate is such that individuals have no incentive either to issue or to buy nominal debt contracts. We will use the model to price nominal bonds at the end of this section.

4.2. THE ONE-MONEY MONETARY ECONOMY

 

 

 

115

and the lump-sum monetary transfer

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Wt =

Pt−1xt−1xt−1 + ωyt−1qt−1yt−1)

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Pt

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

|

 

 

 

 

{z

 

 

 

 

 

 

}

 

∆Mt

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Dividends

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

+ ω e

+ ω

yt−1

e

+

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

.

(4.26)

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

xt−1 t

 

 

 

 

t

 

 

 

 

 

2Pt

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

dividend share values

 

 

 

|

 

{z

 

}

 

 

 

 

 

Money transfer

 

 

 

 

Ex- |

 

{z

 

}

 

 

 

In the securities market, the domestic household allocates Wt towards cash mt to Þnance shopping plans and to equities

Wt =

mt

+ ωxtet + ωy e .

(4.27)

Pt t t

The household knows that the amount of cash required to Þnance the current period consumption plan is

mt = Pt(cxt + qtcyt).

(4.28)

The cash-in-advance constraint is said to bind. Substituting (4.28) into (4.27), and equating the result to (4.26) eliminates mt and gives the simpler consolidated budget constraint

c + q c + ω

e + ω

e =

Pt−1

x

+ ω

q y

]

xt t yt

xt t

 

yt

t

Pt

xt−1 t−1

 

yt−1 t−1 t−1

 

+

∆Mt

+ ω

 

e + ω

 

e .

 

 

(4.29)

 

 

 

 

 

 

2Pt

 

xt−1 t

yt−1

t

 

 

 

 

The domestic household’s problem is therefore to maximize

 

 

 

 

 

jX

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

(4.30)

 

 

 

Et

βju(cxt+j, cyt+j) ,

 

 

 

 

 

=0

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

subject to (4.29). As before, the terms that matter at date t are

 

u(cxt, cyt) + βEtu(cxt+1, cyt+1),

 

so you can substitute (4.29) into the utility function to eliminate cxt and

 

cxt+1 and to transform the problem into one of unconstrained optimiza-

 

tion. The Euler equations characterizing optimal household behavior

(81-83)

are

 

116

 

 

 

 

 

CHAPTER 4. THE LUCAS MODEL

 

cyt : qtu1(cxt, cyt) = u2(cxt, cyt),

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

(4.31)

 

ωxt : etu1(cxt, cyt) = βEt "u1(cxt+1, cyt+1) ÃPt+1 xt + et+1!# ,

(4.32)

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Pt

 

 

 

 

 

 

ωyt : et u1(cxt, cyt) = βEt "u1(cxt+1, cyt+1) ÃPt+1 qtyt + et+1!#

.(4.33)

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Pt

 

 

 

 

 

 

The foreign household solves an analogous problem. Using the for-

 

eign cash-in-advance constraint

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

m

= Pt(c + qtc ).

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

(4.34)

 

 

 

 

 

t

 

 

t

 

 

 

yt

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

the consolidated budget constraint for the foreign household is

 

 

 

c

+ q c

+ ω e + ω e

=

Pt−1

 

x

+ ω

q y

]

 

xt

t yt

 

xt t

yt t

 

Pt

 

xt−1 t−1

 

yt−1 t−1 t−1

 

 

 

+

∆Mt

+ ω

 

et + ω

 

e .

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

(4.35)

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

2Pt

xt−1

 

yt−1

t

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

The job is to maximize

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Et

 

βju(cxt+j, cyt+j) ,

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

jX

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

=0

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

subject to (4.35).

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

(84-86)

The foreign household’s problem generates a symmetric set of Euler

equations

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

c :

qtu1(c

, c

) = u2(c , c ),

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

yt

xt

yt

 

 

xt

yt

 

 

 

 

 

ÃPt+1 xt + et+1!# ,

 

 

ωxt :

etu1(cxt, cyt) = βEt

 

"u1(cxt+1, cyt+1)

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Pt

 

 

 

 

 

 

ωyt :

et u1(cxt, cyt) = βEt "u1

(cxt+1, cyt+1)

ÃPt+1 qtyt + et+1!# .

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Pt

 

 

 

 

 

 

The adding-up constraints that complete the model are

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

1

 

=

ωxt + ωxt,

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

1

 

=

ωyt + ω ,

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

yt

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Mt

 

= mt + m ,

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

t

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

xt

 

= cxt

+ c

 

,

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

xt

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

yt

 

= cyt

+ c .

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

yt

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

4.2. THE ONE-MONEY MONETARY ECONOMY

117

To solve the model, aggregate the cash-in-advance constraints over the home and foreign agents and use the adding-up constraints to get

Mt = Pt(xt + qtyt).

(4.36)

This is the quantity equation for the world economy where velocity is always 1. The single money generates no new idiosyncratic countryspeciÞc risk. The equilibrium established for the barter economy (constant and equal portfolio shares) is still the perfect risk-pooling equi-

librium

ωxt = ωxt = ωyt = ωyt = 12,

cxt = cxt = x2t , cyt = cyt = y2t .

The only thing that has changed are the equity pricing formulae, which now incorporate an ‘inßation premium.’ The inßation premium arises because the nominal dividends of the current period must be carried over into the next period at which time their real value can potentially be eroded by an inßation shock.

Solution under constant relative risk aversion utility. Under the utility

function (4.22), the real exchange rate is qt =

1−θ

xt

 

 

 

 

 

θ

 

 

yt . Substituting (87)

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

h

 

i ³

 

P

 

M

 

xt+1

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

´t

 

 

t

this into (4.36), the inverse of the gross inßation rate is

Pt+1

=

Mt+1

xt .

Together, these expressions can be used to rewrite the equity pricing

equations as

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

e

 

"

 

C

 

(1−γ)

Ã

M

 

e

 

!# ,

 

 

 

 

 

 

t

= βEt

µ

t+1

 

t

+

t+1

 

 

(4.37)

 

 

x

C

M

 

 

x

 

 

 

 

t

 

 

 

t

 

 

t+1

 

 

 

t+1

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

e

 

 

 

Ct+1

(1−γ)

 

Mt

 

 

 

e +1

 

 

 

 

 

 

t

= βEt

"

µ

 

 

Ã

 

 

 

+

 

 

t

 

!# .

 

(4.38)

 

q

y

C

 

M

 

 

q

 

y

 

 

 

t

t

 

 

 

t

 

 

t+1

 

 

t+1 t+1

 

 

 

 

To price nominal bonds, you are looking for the shadow price of a hypothetical nominal bond such that the public willingly keeps it in zero net supply. Let bt be the nominal price of a bond that pays one dollar at the end of the period. The utility cost of buying the bond is u1(cxt, cyt)bt/Pt.

118

CHAPTER 4. THE LUCAS MODEL

In equilibrium, this is o set by the discounted expected marginal utility of the one-dollar payo , βEt[u1(cxt+1, cyt+1)/Pt+1]. Under the constant relative risk aversion utility function (4.22) we have

 

"

µ

C

(1−γ) M

# .

 

bt = βEt

t+1

 

t

(4.39)

C

M

 

 

t

 

t+1

 

 

If it is the nominal interest rate, then bt = (1 + it)−1. Nominal interest rates will be positive in all states of nature if bt < 1 and is likely to be true when the endowment growth rate and monetary growth rates are positive.

4.3The Two-Money Monetary Economy

To address exchange rate issues, you need to introduce a second national currency. Let the home country money be the ‘dollar’ and the foreign country money be the ‘euro.’ We now amend the transactions technology to require that the home country’s x—goods can only be purchased with dollars and the foreign country’s y—goods can only be purchased with euros. In addition, x−dividends are paid out in dollars and y−dividends are paid out in euros. Agents can acquire the foreign currency required to Þnance consumption plans during securities market trading.

Let Pt be the dollar price of x, Pt be the euro price of y, and St be the exchange rate expressed as the dollar price of euros. Mt is the outstanding stock of dollars, Nt is the outstanding stock of euros and they evolve over time according to

Mt = λtMt−1, and Nt = λt Nt−1,

where (λt, λt ) are exogenous random gross rates of change in M and

N.

If the domestic household received transfers only of M, it faces foreign purchasing-power risk because it it also needs N to buy y-goods. Introducing the second currency creates a new country-speciÞc risk that households will want to hedge. The complete markets paradigm allows markets to develop whenever there is a demand for a product. The

4.3. THE TWO-MONEY MONETARY ECONOMY

119

products that individuals desire are claims to future dollar and euro transfers.5 So to develop this idea, let rt be the price of a claim to all future dollar transfers in terms of x and rt be the price to all future euro transfers in terms of x. Let there be one perfectly divisible claim outstanding for each of these monetary transfer streams. Let the domestic agent hold ψMt claims on the dollar streams and ψNt claims on the euro streams whereas the foreign agent holds ψMt claims on the dollar stream and ψNt claims on the euro stream. Initially, the home agent is endowed with ψM = 1, ψN = 0 and the foreign agent has ψN = 1, ψM = 0 which they are free to trade.

Now to develop the problem confronting the domestic household, note that current-period wealth consists of nominal dividends paid from equity ownership carried over from last period, current period monetary transfers the market value of equity and monetary transfer claims

 

 

P

t−1

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

S P

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

W =

 

 

 

ω x

 

 

 

+

 

t t−1

ω

yt−1

y

t−1

 

t

 

 

 

Pt

 

xt−1 t−1

 

 

 

 

Pt

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

}

 

 

 

|ψ

 

 

∆M

 

 

 

ψ{z

 

S ∆N

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Dividends

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

+

 

 

 

Mt−1 t

+

 

 

Nt−1 t

t

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

|

 

 

 

 

Pt

 

{z

 

 

 

Pt

 

}

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Monetary Transfers

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

+ ωxt−1et + ωyt−1et + ψMt−1rt + ψNt−1rt .

(4.40)

 

|

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

{z

 

 

 

 

 

}

 

 

 

 

 

Market

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

value of securities

 

This wealth is then allocated to stocks, claims to future monetary transfers, dollars and euros for shopping in securities market trading according to

Wt = ωxtet + ωyte + ψMtrt + ψNtr +

mt

+

ntSt

.

(4.41)

 

 

t

t

Pt

 

Pt

 

 

 

 

 

The current values of xt, yt, Mt, and Nt are revealed before trading occurs so domestic households acquire the exact amount of dollars and euros required to Þnance current period consumption plans. In equilibrium, we have the binding cash-in-advance constraints

mt = Ptcxt,

(4.42)

5In the real world, this type of hedge might be constructed by taking appropriate positions in futures contracts for foreign currencies.

120

CHAPTER 4.

THE LUCAS MODEL

 

nt = P cyt,

(4.43)

 

t

 

which you can use to eliminate mt and nt from the allocation of current

period wealth to rewrite (4.41) as

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

StP

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Wt = cxt +

 

 

t

cyt + ωxtet + ωyte + ψMtrt + ψNtr .

 

(4.44)

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Pt

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

t

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

t

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

|

 

 

{z

 

}

 

|

 

 

 

{z

 

 

}

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Goods

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

|

 

 

 

{z

 

 

 

 

}

 

 

 

Equity

 

 

 

Money transfers

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

The consolidated budget constraint of the home individual is therefore

 

 

 

 

S P

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

P

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

c

+

 

 

t t

c + ω

 

 

e + ω e

+ ψ r + ψ r

=

 

t−1

ω x

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

xt

 

 

 

 

Pt

 

yt

 

 

xt

 

t

yt

 

t

 

Mt

t

 

Nt t

 

 

Pt

 

 

xt−1

t−1

 

 

 

 

 

 

S P

 

 

 

 

y

 

 

+

ψ

Mt−1

∆M

t +

 

ψ

S ∆N

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

+ t

t−1 ω

yt−1

t−1

 

 

 

 

 

Nt−1 t

 

 

t

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Pt

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Pt

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Pt

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

xt−1et + ωyt−1et + ψxt−1rt + ψyt−1rt .

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

(4.45)

 

The domestic household’s problem is to maximize

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

jX

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

(4.46)

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Et βju(cxt+j, cyt+j)

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

=0

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

(88-92)

subject to (4.45). The associated Euler equations are

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

StP

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

cyt :

 

t

u1(cxt, cyt) = u2(cxt, cyt),

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

(4.47)

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

ωxt :

 

Pt

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

ÃPt+1 xt + et+1

!# ,

 

(4.48)

 

etu1(cxt, cyt) = βEt "u1(cxt+1, cyt+1)

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Pt

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

ωyt :

et u1(cxt, cyt) = βEt "u1(cxt+1, cyt+1)

Ã

 

Pt t+1t

yt + et+1!# , (4.49)

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

S +1P

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

ψMt :

rtu1(cxt, cyt) = βEt "u1(cxt+1, cyt+1)

Ã

 

 

Pt+1

+ rt+1

!# ,

 

(4.50)

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

∆Mt+1

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

ψNt :

rt u1(cxt, cyt) = βEt "u1(cxt+1, cyt+1)

Ã

 

 

Pt t+1 t+1

+ rt+1

!#(4. .51)

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

∆N +1S

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

The foreign agent solves the analogous problem which generate a set of symmetric Euler equations, do not need to be stated here.

4.3. THE TWO-MONEY MONETARY ECONOMY

121

We know that in equilibrium, the cash-in-advance constraints bind.

The cash-in-advance constraints for the foreign agent are

 

 

m = Ptc ,

 

(4.52)

 

t

xt

 

 

 

nt = Pt cyt

 

(4.53)

In addition, we have the adding-up constraints

 

1

=

ψMt + ψMt,

 

1

=

ψNt + ψNt,

 

xt

= cxt + c

,

 

 

 

xt

 

 

yt

= cyt + c

,

 

 

 

yt

 

 

Mt

= mt + mt ,

 

Nt

= nt + n .

 

 

 

 

t

 

 

Together, the adding-up constraints and the cash-in-advance constraints give a unit-velocity quantity equation for each country

Mt = Ptxt Nt = Pt yt,

which can be used to eliminate the endogenous nominal price levels from the Euler equations.

The equilibrium where people are able to pool and insure against

their country-speciÞc risks is given by

 

 

1

(93)

ωxt = ω

= ωyt = ω

= ψMt = ψ

= ψNt = ψ

=

.

 

xt

yt

Mt

Nt

2

 

 

 

 

Both the domestic and foreign representative households own half of the domestic endowment stream, half of the foreign endowment stream, half of all future domestic monetary transfers and half of all future foreign monetary transfers. In short, they split the world’s resources

in half so the pooling equilibrium supports the symmetric allocation

cxt = cxt = x2t and cyt = cyt = y2t .

To solve for the nominal exchange rate St, we know by (4.47) that

the real exchange rate is

 

 

 

 

 

 

u2(cxt, cyt)

StP

StNtxt

 

 

 

 

=

t

=

 

.

(4.54)

 

 

Mtyt

 

u1(cxt, cyt)

Pt

 

 

122

CHAPTER 4.

THE LUCAS MODEL

Rearranging (4.54) gives the nominal exchange rate

St =

u2(cxt, cyt)

 

Mt

 

yt

.

(4.55)

 

 

 

 

u1(cxt, cyt) Nt xt

 

As in the monetary approach, the fundamental determinants of the nominal exchange rate are relative money supplies and relative GDPs. The two major di erences are Þrst that in the Lucas model the exchange rate depends on preferences (utility), and second that it does not depend explicitly on expectations of the future.

The solution under constant relative risk aversion utility. Using the utility function (4.22), the equilibrium real exchange rate is qt = ((1 −

(94) θ)/θ)(xt/yt). The income terms cancel out and the exchange rate is

St =

(1 − θ)

 

Mt

.

(4.56)

 

 

 

θ Nt

 

The Euler equations are

et

xt et

qtyt

rt

xt rt

xt

=βEt

=βEt

=βEt

=βEt

"µCt+1 (1−γ)

Ct

"µCt+1 (1−γ)

Ct

"µCt+1 (1−γ)

Ct

Ct+1 (1−γ)

Ct

Ã!#

 

Mt

 

 

+

 

 

et+1

 

 

,

(4.57)

 

Mt+1

 

 

xt+1

 

Ã

 

 

 

 

 

 

!# ,

 

Nt

 

 

+

 

et+1

 

(4.58)

Nt+1

 

qt+1yt+1

Ã

∆Mt+1

 

+

rt+1

!# ,

(4.59)

Mt+1

xt+1

Ã

 

θ

 

 

 

Nt+1

 

xt+1

!#

 

1

θ ∆N

 

r

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

t+1

+

t+1

. (4.60)

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Just as you can calculate the equilibrium price of nominal bonds even though they are not traded in equilibrium, you can compute the equilibrium forward exchange rate even though there is no explicit forward market. To do this, let bt be the date t dollar price of a 1-period nominal discount bond that pays one dollar at the beginning of period t+1, and let bt be the date t euro price of a 1-period nominal discount bond that pays one euro at the beginning of period t+1. By covered interest parity (1.2 ), the one-period ahead forward exchange rate is,

 

b

 

Ft = St

t

.

(4.61)

 

 

bt

 

4.3. THE TWO-MONEY MONETARY ECONOMY

123

The equilibrium bond prices are

bt = βEt

"µCt+1 1−γ

Ct

bt = βEt

"

Ct+1

1−γ

C

 

µ

t

 

Mt

# ,

(4.62)

Mt+1

 

Nt

# .

(4.63)

 

Nt+1

124

CHAPTER 4. THE LUCAS MODEL

Table 4.1: Notation for the Lucas Model

x The domestic good.

yThe foreign good.

qRelative price of y in terms of x.

cx

Home consumption of home good.

cy

Home consumption of foreign good.

CDomestic Cobb-Douglas consumption index, cθxc(1y −θ).

C

Foreign Cobb-Douglas consumption index, cxθcy(1−θ).

cx

Foreign consumption of home good.

cy

Foreign consumption of foreign good.

ωx

Shares of home Þrm held by home agent.

ωy

Shares of foreign Þrm held by home agent.

ωx

Shares of home Þrm held by foreign agent.

ωy

Shares of foreign Þrm held by foreign agent.

s

Nominal exchange rate. Dollar price of euro.

ePrice of home Þrm equity in terms of x.

e

Price of foreign Þrm equity in terms of x.

PNominal Price of x in dollars.

P

Nominal Price of y in euros.

M

Dollars in circulation.

NEuros in circulation.

λt

Rate of growth of M.

λt

Rate of growth of N.

mDollars held by domestic household.

m

Dollars held by foreign household.

nEuros held by domestic household.

n

Euros held by foreign household.

rt

Price of claim to future dollar transfers in terms of x.

rt

Price of claim to future euro transfers in terms of x.

ψMt

Shares of dollar transfer stream held by home agent.

ψNt

Shares of euro transfer stream held by home agent.

ψMt

Shares of dollar transfer stream held by foreign agent.

ψNt

Shares of euro transfer stream held by foreign agent.

bt

Price of one-period nominal bond with one-dollar payo .